Vol.2 , No. 5, Publication Date: Sep. 22, 2015, Page: 40-55
[1] | Diana Loubaki, Department of Fundamental Analysis in Economics, University Marien N’Gouabi, Brazzaville, Congo; Centre d'Economie du Développement et de la Soutenabilité de la Croissance, Clamart, France. |
This article is a global economic development theory built on a mixture of historical observation, scientific results as well as modern growth and the brain drain theories interaction. The results found are: ex-ante and ex-post multiple equibria define multiple take-off locus over time. Once the dynamical paths converge toward a given locus, thus joins the convergence club in economic performance level. Finally, comparative development presents three main economic performance levels where the highest is shared among Western countries, between the highest and the world threshold is the one shared by the Asian emerging countries, Latin American countries settled on the threshold and African countries remain at the bottom. Therefore, a theory is provided to lift the lowest dynamical path toward the equilibrium on the basis of the capacity to innovate through R&D, knowledge externalities, adoption and absorption of new innovations in production sector. Consequently, the model provides theoretical foundations of the empirically observed emerging countries in economic globalization context fact the theory couldn’t explain until now.
Keywords
Ex-Ante Multiple Equilibria, Ex-Post Multiple Equilibria, Take-Off, Technology Adoption, Technology Absorption, Knowledge Externalities, Diaspora, Comparative Development
Reference
[01] | Acemoglu, D. (2005): Institutions and Growth, in Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S., eds.: Handbook of Economic Growth, North Holland. |
[02] | Agrawal, A., D. Kapur, and J. McHale (2008): Brain Drain or Brain Bank: The Impact of Skilled Emigration on Poor-Country Innovation, NBER Working Paper No 14592, December. |
[03] | Aghion, P., and Howitt, P. 1992. A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction. Econometrica 60 (2): 323–51. |
[04] | Arrow, K. J., 1962. The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing, Review of Economic Studies 29, 155-173. |
[05] | Azariadis, C. and Drazen, A., (1990): Threshold externalities in economic development, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 501-526. |
[06] | Beine, M., Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H., (2001): Brain drain and economic growth: theory and evidence, Journal of Development Economics, 64, 1: 275-89. |
[07] | Berry, A.R. and Soligo, R., (1969): Some welfare aspects of international migration, Journal of Political Economy, 77, 5: 778-94. |
[08] | Bhagwati and Hanson, eds.: Skilled immigration: problems, prospects and policies, Oxford University Press, pp. 3-11. |
[09] | Bhagwati, J.N. and Hamada, K., (1974): The brain drain, international integration of markets for professionals and unemployment, Journal of Development Economics, 1, 1:19-42. |
[10] | Chen, H.-J. (2006): International migration and economic growth: a source country perspective, Journal of Population Economics, 19: 725-48. |
[11] | Domingues Dos Santos, M. and Postel-Vinay, F., (2003): Migration as a source of growth: the perspective of a developing country, Journal of Population Economics, 16, 1: 161-75. |
[12] | Domingues Dos Santos, M. and Postel-Vinay, F., (2004): The impact of temporary migration on human capital accumulation and economic development, Brussels Economic Review, 47, 1: 77-88. |
[13] | Fernando, A.; Buera F. J., and Lucas, R. E., Jr. 2014. Idea Flows, Economic Growth, and Trade, Unpublished. |
[14] | Barro, R. J., and Sala-i-Martin, X., (1991), Convergence across States and Regions.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1, 107–182. |
[15] | Barro, R. J., and Sala-i-Martin, X., (1992a). “Convergence.” Journal of Political Economy, 100, April, 223–251. |
[16] | Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X, 2004, Economic Growth, MIT Press. |
[17] | Braconier, H.; and Forslid, R.; 2005, Multinationals, Endogenous Growth, and Technological Spillovers: Theory and Evidence; Review of International Economics 13 (5): 945–63. |
[18] | Richard, B. E., and Nicoud, F. R.; 2008, Trade and Growth with Heterogeneous Firms, Journal of International Economics 74 (1): 21–34. |
[19] | Chen, H., 2008, The endogenous probability of migration and economic growth, Economic Modeling Journal. |
[20] | Coe, D. T., and Helpman, E.; 1995; International R&D Spillovers; European Economic Review 39 (5): 859–87. |
[21] | Docquier, F., and Dalacroix, D., (2012), Do Brain Drain and Poverty Result from Coordination Failure?, The Journal of Economic Growth, 17(1), 1-26. |
[22] | Domar, E. D., (1946), Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth and Employment, Econometrica, 49, p. 14-33. |
[23] | Eaton, J. and Kortum, S.; (1999), International Technology Diffusion: Theory and Measurement; International Economic Review 40 (3): 537–70. |
[24] | Eaton, J., and Kortum, S.;.(2002), Technology, Geography, and Trade. Econometrica 70 (5): 1741–79. |
[25] | Eicher, T., (1996), Interaction between endogenous human capital and technological change, Review of Economic Studies, 63, 127-144. |
[26] | Feenstra, R. C. (1996), Trade and Uneven Growth, Journal of Development Economics 49 (1): 229–56. |
[27] | Garcia Pires, A., (2015), Brain Drain and Brain Waste, Journal of Economic Development, 40(1). |
[28] | Grossman, G. M., and Helpman, E., (1991a), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. |
[29] | Grossman, G. M., and Helpman E.; (1991b), Trade, Knowledge Spillovers, and Growth, European Economic Review 35 (2–3): 517–26. |
[30] | Grossman, G. M., and Helpman, E.; (2014), Growth, Trade and Inequality. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 20502. |
[31] | Grossman, G. M., and Helpman, E., (2015), Globalization and Growth, American Economic Review, 105(5): 100–104. |
[32] | Grubel, H. and Scott, A., (1966): The international flow of human capital, American Economic Review, 56: 268-74. |
[33] | Haque, N. U and Kim, S., (1995): Human capital light: impact of migration on income and growth, IMF Staff Papers, 42, 3: 577-607. |
[34] | Helpman, E., (2004), The Mystery of Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Belknap by Harvard University Press. |
[35] | Harrod, R. F., (1939), An Essay in Dynamic Theory, Economic Journal, 49, p.14-33. |
[36] | Kanbur, R. and H. Rapoport (2005): Migration selectivity and the evolution of spatial inequality, Journal of Economic Geography, 5, 1: 43-57. |
[37] | Keller, W.; (2010), International Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and Technology Spillovers. In Handbook of the Economics of Innovation. Vol. 2, edited by Bronwyn H. Hall and Nathan Rosenberg, 793–829. Amsterdam: Elsevier B. V.. |
[38] | Kim, K. H. (1976), “The Economics of the Brain Drain: Pros, Cons and Remedies,” The Journal of Economic Development, 1 (1), 55-80. |
[39] | Kerr, W. R. (2008): Ethnic Scientific Communities and International Technology Diffusion, Review of Economics and Statistics, 90: 518. 537. |
[40] | Loubaki, D., (2012), On the Mechanics of the Brain Drain Reduction in Poorest Developing Countries, Journal of Economic Development, 37, (3), September 2012, p.75-105. |
[41] | Loubaki, D., (2015), Poverty Reduction, Brain Drain and Development, American Journal of Economics, Finance and Management, Vol. 1, No. 5, 2015, pp. 537-553. |
[42] | Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988), On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1): 3–42. |
[43] | Mc Cullock, R. and Yellen, J. T., (1977): Factor mobility, regional development and the distribution of income, Journal of Political Economy, 85, 1: 79-96. |
[44] | Melitz, M. J., (2003), The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity; Econometrica 71 (6): 1695–1725. |
[45] | Miyagiwa, K., (1991), Scale economies in education and the brain drain problem, International Economic Review, 32, 3: 743-59. |
[46] | Mountford, A. (1995): Can a brain drain be good for growth?, NBER Working Paper No 9508, Tilburg University, January.6. |
[47] | Peretto, P. F., and Valente, S., (2011), Resources, Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy; Journal of Monetary Economics 58 (4): 387–99. |
[48] | Perla, J., Tonetti, C. and Waugh, M. E., (2014), Equilibrium Technology Diffusion, Trade, and Growth, Unpublished. |
[49] | Romer, P. M., (1990), Endogenous Technical Change, Journal of Political Economy 98 (5, Part 2): S71–S102. |
[50] | Romer, P. M. (1986): Increasing returns and long-run growth, Journal of Political Economy, 94, 5: 1002-37. |
[51] | Sampson, T., (2014), Dynamic Selection: An Idea Flows Theory of Entry, Trade and Growth, Unpublished. |
[52] | Sachs, J. (2005) The End of Poverty: How we Can Make it Happen in Our Lifetime, London: Penguin Books. |
[53] | Sachs, J. and Warner, A., (1995), Economic reform and the process of global integration, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity, 1, 1-95. |
[54] | Smulders, S. and Bovenberg, A. L., Environmental quality and pollution-augmenting technological change in a two-sector endogenous growth model, Journal of Public Economics, 57, 1995, 369-391. |
[55] | Solow, R. M., 1956, A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70 (1), 65-94. |
[56] | Stark, O. and Wang, Y., (2002): Inducing human capital formation: migration as a substitute for subsidies, Journal Public Economics, 86, 1: 29-46. |
[57] | Young, A. 1991, Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2): 369–405. |